Article Text

PDF

Introduction to health economics for the medical practitioner
  1. D P Kernick
  1. Correspondence to:
 Dr D P Kernick, St Thomas’ Medical Group, Cowick Street, Exeter EX4 1HJ, UK; 
 su1838{at}eclipse.co.uk

Abstract

Against a background of increasing demands on limited resources, health economics is exerting an influence on decision making at all levels of health care. Health economics seeks to facilitate decision making by offering an explicit decision making framework based on the principle of efficiency. It is not the only consideration but it is an important one and practitioners will need to have an understanding of its basic principles and how it can impact on clinical decision making. This article reviews some of the basic principles of health economics and in particular economic evaluation.

  • health economics
  • economic evaluation
  • GP, general practitioner
  • QALY, quality adjusted life year

Statistics from Altmetric.com

WHAT IS HEALTH ECONOMICS?

Health economics is the discipline of economics applied to the topic of health care. Broadly defined, economics concerns how society allocates its resources among alternative uses. Scarcity of these resources provides the foundation of economic theory and from this starting point, three basic questions arise:

  • What goods and services shall we produce?

  • How shall we produce them?

  • Who shall receive them?

Health economics addresses these questions primarily from the perspective of efficiency—maximising the benefits from available resources (or ensuring benefits gained exceed benefits forgone). Equity concerns are also recognised—what is a fair distribution of resources. Considerations of equity often conflict with efficiency directives. However, due to the contested nature of this area and the difficulties in quantifying equity dimensions, this element has not been a major focus of health economist’s work.

WHY IS HEALTH ECONOMICS IMPORTANT?

Thirty years ago there were limited options for doctors making treatment choices and patients did as they were told. Any values that contributed to the decision making process were implicit and determined by the physician. However, against a background of limited health care resources, an empowered consumer and an increasing array of intervention options (see fig 1) there is a need for decisions to be taken more openly and fairly.

Figure 1

Diagrammatic background to health economics—increasing demands on limited resources (area of each circle reflects size of each variable).

The importance of the economic model is that it provides useful insights into how health care can be organised and financed and provides a framework to address a broad range of issues in an explicit and consistent manner. Organisational changes such as the development of the National Institute for Clinical Excellence and the devolution of decision making to primary care organisations have led to an increasing interest in the subject and its influence on health care organisation and decision making.

WHAT DO HEALTH ECONOMISTS DO?

Health economists are interested in the production of health at a number of levels. For example:

  • What is health and how do we put a value on it?

  • What influences health other than health care?

  • What influences the demand for health care and health care seeking behaviour?

  • What influences the supply of health care? (The behaviour of doctors and health care providers.)

  • Alternative ways of production and delivery of health care.

  • Planning, budgeting, and monitoring of health care.

  • Economic evaluation—relating the costs and benefits of alternative ways of delivering health care.

Although all of these elements offer useful insights into the delivery of health care, it is economic evaluation that provides the bulk of health economists’ work and is of most relevance to managers and practitioners. This exercise offers a framework for measuring, valuing, and comparing the costs (negative consequences) and benefits (positive consequences) of different health care interventions. In this way we can assess whether the benefits gained by introducing an intervention outweigh the benefits that are foregone. A discussion of economic evaluation and its principles forms the rest of this paper.

CONCEPT OF ECONOMIC EVALUATION

The concept of economic evaluation underpins efficiency choices in health care.1 It relates the benefits of alternative interventions to the resources incurred in their production (see fig 2).

Figure 2

Economic analysis relates inputs (resources) to outputs (benefits and the values attached to them) of alternative interventions to facilitate decision making when resources are scarce.

We will first explore three principles that are an important part of any economic analysis before looking at the types of economic studies.

Opportunity cost

Health economists stress the importance of value unlike accountants who are just interested in money. When budgets are finite, resources invested into one area will be at the expense of a loss of opportunity in another and resources should be valued in terms of this lost opportunity—the opportunity cost.2 For example, if the Cardio-Vascular National Service Framework dictates an increase in statin prescribing, we should think carefully about what we are having to go without to provide the additional service and value it in terms of this lost opportunity.

Perspective

Whenever an economic question is being asked it is important to think carefully about the viewpoint of the analysis. This will dictate which costs and benefits are important. The perspective of the patient, health authority, NHS, and society may differ.

For example, from the perspective of a general practitioner (GP) practice, the cost of a GP is £21 per hour. If the health authority perspective is taken then capital costs and management overheads are relevant and the cost will be £53 per hour. From a NHS perspective, undergraduate and postgraduate training costs will become relevant which must be annuitised across the expected working life time and the cost is £69 per hour.

Different perspectives will give different answers when deciding between treatment options and decision makers must be clear on the viewpoint that is taken.

Marginal analysis

The relationship between resources invested into an intervention and the benefit that is incurred is rarely linear. As decisions in health are usually whether to expand or contract existing services, it is important to consider how increments in benefit change with increment in resource allocation and not the average benefits that are incurred by average costs. This is known as a marginal analysis.3

Figure 3 shows an example where the benefits in terms of years of life saved are plotted against resources invested in statin treatment. Three points are highlighted for cost/life year saved where resources are invested into very high risk, low risk, and very low risk patients.4

Figure 3

Costs and benefits in terms of life years saved from statin treatment. Costs/life years saved are shown for very high risk, low risk, and very low risk patients.

WHAT ARE THE DIFFERENT TYPES OF ECONOMIC EVALUATION?

We now explore the different types of economic evaluation which take their name from the way in which benefits are measured (see table 1).

Table 1

The four types of formal economic evaluation

(1) Cost minimisation analysis

In a cost minimisation analysis, the consequences of two or more interventions being compared are equivalent. The analysis therefore focuses on costs alone, and the cheapest option is chosen.

(2) Cost effectiveness analysis

Cost effectiveness analysis is the most common type of analysis and is used to compare drugs or programmes which have a common health outcome (for example, reduction in blood pressure, life years saved).5 Results are usually presented in the form of a ratio (for example, costs per life year gained). For example, it has been estimated that coronary care units cost £4900 per life year saved compared with neonatal intensive care units at £11 500 per life year saved.

Often, intermediate or surrogate outcomes such as cases detected, reduction in cholesterol are measured and it is important to ensure that these intermediate measures have clinical meaning in terms of long term outcome for patients.

(3) Cost utility analysis

Often interventions impact both on quality and quantity of life. A cost utility analysis can be used to assess costs and benefits of interventions where there is no single outcome of interest and is useful comparing different programmes across different treatment areas.6

The most frequently used measure is the quality adjusted life year (QALY). Benefits are measured based on impact on length and quality of life to produce an overall index of health gain. A health state is valued between 0 (worst health) and 1 (best health) combined it with the length of time in that state. For example, a drug that yields an improvement in health state value of 0.6 over a period of 10 years would yield 6 QALYs. It has been estimated that coronary artery bypass grafting costs £2000 per QALY compared with £1100 for hip replacement.

QALYs reflect people’s preferences for different health states but their use remains contested in a number of areas.

When acting on the results of cost effectiveness and cost utility studies, if two treatments A and B are compared and costs are lower for A and outcomes better, then treatment A will be preferable. If, as is more commonly the case with a new drug, costs are higher for one treatment, but benefits are higher too, it is necessary to calculate how much extra benefits is obtained for the extra cost. A decision then needs to be made as to whether this addition in benefit is worth paying for.7

Table 2 shows some tentative estimates of the cost/QALY of a range of interventions.

Table 2

A cost effectiveness league table. Cost per quality adjusted life year (QALY) of competing therapies—some tentative estimates

(4) Cost benefit analysis

In a Cost Benefit Analysis, attempts are made to value all the costs and consequences of an intervention in monetary terms. If the benefits are less than the costs then the intervention is acceptable.8 For example, a study of the impact of a triptan at a cost of £4 per attack in the treatment of migraine found an economic gain in terms of work absence saved of £12.50 compared with placebo.9 However, the data requirements for this approach are often large and methodological issues around the valuation of non-monetary benefits such as lives saved makes this method problematic.

(5) Cost consequences analysis

Although this approach is not a formal method of economic analysis and as such is not shown in table 1, it is one that may be more attractive to decision makers who can apply their own weight to the various outcomes. In some cases, studies consider many disparate outcomes that cannot be condensed into a single measure of benefit.10 In this case, costs and outcomes are presented in a disaggregated form, which avoids the need to represent results as a single index but which makes decision-making more difficult. Never the less it is an approach which reflects how decisions are made in the real world. Table 3 shows how a cost consequence study might look in practice.

Table 3

An example of a cost consequence study—transferring gastroscopy services to primary care

A PRACTICAL EXAMPLE—TREATING RAISED CHOLESTEROL WITH STATINS

We conclude with a practical example demonstrating how health economics can facilitate a health care decision. Table 4 shows the cost effectiveness of treating raised cholesterol with statins at various levels of population risk.11 How can we decide what risk should be targeted?

Table 4

Cost effectiveness of treating patients with raised cholesterol at differing annual risks of an event

Table 5 shows some possible alternative uses of our money. Using the principle of opportunity cost we can get some sort of idea of what we would have to forego for treating each level of risk. Clearly there are many other issues to be taken into consideration but this information can help to frame the decision.

Table 5

Estimates of the cost effectiveness of some competing interventions

However, it should be born in mind that economic analysis focuses on efficiency which does not necessarily correlate with affordability. Pickin used existing data to calculate the cost of treating the population with statins at different levels of risk. Table 6 shows the number of the population needed to treat for each risk level and the cost. Although treating the population who have a 2% risk would be efficient in terms of cost/life year saved when compared to other interventions, it would consume an unacceptable proportion of our resources.

Table 6

Affordability of treating raised cholesterol—implications for a typical health authority of treating raised cholesterol

Key references

CONCLUSION

Difficult choices in health care are inevitable and there is an increasing emphasis on making decisions explicit and fair. Health economics suffers from a number of methodological limitations but it can offer us useful concepts and principles which help us think more clearly about the implications of resource decisions we make. An understanding of some basic economic principles is essential for all practitioners not only to understand the useful concepts the discipline can offer but to appreciate its limitations and shortcomings.

REFERENCES

View Abstract

Request permissions

If you wish to reuse any or all of this article please use the link below which will take you to the Copyright Clearance Center’s RightsLink service. You will be able to get a quick price and instant permission to reuse the content in many different ways.